Next: Lower Bounds on Path Length
Up: Introduction
Previous: Introduction
To begin, we first formalise the concepts of
deal and contract path.
Definition 2
Let
be a resource allocation setting.
A
deal is a pair
where
and
are distinct partitions of
.
The effect of implementing the deal
is that the allocation of resources
specified by
is replaced with that specified by
.
Following the notation of
[Endriss & Maudet, 2004b]
for a deal
, we use
to indicate the subset of
involved, i.e.
if and only if
.
Let
be a deal. A contract path realising is a sequence of allocations
in which
and
.
The
length of
, denoted
is
, i.e. the number of
deals in
.
There are two methods which we can use to reduce the number of deals that a single agent may
have to consider in seeking to move from some allocation to another, thereby avoiding the need
to choose from exponentially many alternatives: structural and rationality constraints.
Structural constraints limit the permitted deals to those which bound the number of resources and/or
the number of agents involved, but take no consideration of the view
any agent may have as to whether its allocation has improved. In contrast, rationality constraints
restrict deals
to those in which ``improves'' upon according to particular
criteria. In this article we consider two classes of structural constraint: -contracts, defined
and considered in [Sandholm, 1998], and what we shall refer to as -contracts.
Thus, -contracts involve the transfer of exactly one resource from a particular agent
to another, resulting in the number of deals compatible with any given allocation
being exactly : each of the resources can be reassigned from its current owner to any
of the other agents.
Rationality constraints arise in a number of different ways. For example,
from the standpoint of an individual agent a given deal
may have three different
outcomes:
, i.e.
values the allocation as superior to ;
, i.e. is indifferent between and ; and
, i.e. is worse off after the deal.
When global optima such as utilitarian social welfare are to be maximised, there is the question of
what incentive there is for any agent to accept a deal
under which it is
left with a less valuable resource holding. The standard approach to this latter question
is to introduce the notion of a pay-off function, i.e.
in order for to accept a deal under which it suffers a reduction in utility,
receives some payment sufficient to compensate for its loss. Of course such compensation
must be made by other agents in the system who in providing it do not wish to pay
in excess of any gain. In defining notions of pay-off the interpretation
is that in any transaction each agent makes a payment, : if then
is given in return for accepting a deal; if then contributes
to the amount to be distributed among those agents whose pay-off is negative.
This notion of ``sensible transfer'' is captured by the concept of individual rationality, and
is often defined in terms of an appropriate pay-off vector existing. It is not difficult,
however, to show that such definitions are equivalent to the following.
Definition 4
A deal
is
individually rational (IR) if and only if
.
We shall consider alternative bases for rationality constraints later: these
are primarily of interest within so-called money free settings
(so that compensatory payment for a loss in utility is not an option).
The central issue of interest in this paper concerns the properties of the contract-net graph
when the allowed deals must satisfy both a structural and a rationality
constraint. Thus, if we consider arbitrary predicates on deals
- where the
cases of interest are combining a structural and rationality condition - we have,
Definition 5
For
a predicate over distinct pairs of allocations,
a contract path
realising
is a
-
path
if for each
,
is a
-
deal, that is
holds.
We say that
is
complete if any deal
may be realised by a
-path.
We, further, say that
is
complete with respect to -
deals
(where
is a predicate over distinct pairs of allocations) if any deal
for which
holds may be realised by a
-path.
The main interest in earlier studies of these ideas has been in areas such
as identifying necessary and/or sufficient conditions on deals to be complete with respect to particular
criteria, e.g. [Sandholm, 1998]; and in establishing ``convergence'' and termination
properties, e.g.
[Endriss et al., 2003;
Endriss & Maudet, 2004b] consider deal types, , such that
every maximal1 -path
ends in a Pareto optimal allocation, i.e. one in which any reallocation under which
some agent improves its utility will lead to another agent suffering a loss.
Sandholm [1998] examines how restrictions
e.g. with
if and only if
is an -contract, may affect the existence
of contract paths to realise deals. Of particular interest, from the viewpoint of
heuristics for exploring the contract-net graph, are cases where
if and only if
the deal
is individually rational. For the case of -contracts the following are known:
Theorem 1
- a.
- -contracts are complete.
- b.
- IR -contracts are not complete with respect to IR deals.
In the consideration of algorithmic and complexity issues
presented in [Dunne et al., 2003]
one difficulty with attempting to formulate reallocation
plans by rational -contracts is already apparent, that is:
Theorem 2
Even in the case
and with monotone utility functions
the problem of deciding if an IR
-contract path exists to realise the IR deal
is
NP-hard.
Thus deciding if any rational plan is possible is already computationally hard. In this article
we demonstrate that, even if an appropriate rational plan exists, in extreme cases, there may be
significant problems: the number of deals required could be exponential in the number
of resources, so affecting both the time it will take for the schema outlined to conclude and
the space that an agent will have to dedicate to storing it.
Thus in his proof of Theorem 1 (b), Sandholm observes that when an IR -contract
path exists for a given IR deal, it may be the case that its length exceeds , i.e. some
agent passes a resource to another and then accepts the same resource at a later stage.
The typical form of the results that we derive can be summarised as:
For a structural constraint (-contract or -contract) and
a rationality constraint, e.g. holds if
is individually rational,
there are resource allocation settings
in which
there is a deal
satisfying all of the following.
- a.
-
is a -deal.
- b.
-
can be realised by a contract path on which every deal satisfies the structural
constraint and the rationality constraint .
- c.
- Every such contract path has length at least .
For example, we show
that there are instances for which the shortest IR -contract path has length exponential in
.2In the next section we will be interested in lower bounds on the values of the following functions:
we introduce these in general terms to avoid unnecessary subsequent repetition.
Definition 6
Let
be a resource allocation setting.
Additionally let
and
be two predicates on deals. For a deal
the partial function
is the length of the
shortest -contract path realising
if such a
path exists (and is undefined if no such path is possible). The partial function
is
Finally, the partial function
is
where consideration is restricted to those
-deals
for which a realising
-path exists.
The three measures, , and distinguish different aspects
regarding the length of contract-paths. The function is concerned with -paths
realising a single deal
in a given resource allocation setting
: the
property of interest being the number of deals in the shortest, i.e. optimal length, -path.
We stress that is a partial function whose value is undefined in the event
that
cannot be realised by a -path in the
setting
.
The function is defined in terms of , again in the context of a specific
resource allocation setting. The behaviour of interest for , however, is not simply the length
of -paths realising a specific
but the ``worst-case'' value of for
deals which are -deals.
We note the qualification that is defined only for
-deals that are capable of being realised by -paths,
and thus do not consider cases for which no appropriate
contract path exists. Thus, if it should be the case that no -deal in the setting
can be realised by a -path then
the value
is undefined, i.e.
is also a partial function. We may interpret any upper bound on
in the following terms: if
then
any -deal for which a -path exists can be realised by a -path of length
at most .
Our main interest will centre on which is concerned with the behaviour
of as a function of and and ranges over all -tuples of utility
functions
. Our approach to obtaining
lower bounds for this function is constructive, i.e. for each
that is
considered, we show how the utility functions may be defined in a setting with resources
so as to yield a lower bound on
. In contrast to the measures
and , the function is not described in terms of a single fixed
resource allocation setting. It is, however, still a partial function: depending on
it may be the case that in every agent, resource allocation setting, regardless of
which choice of utility functions is made, there is no -deal,
capable of
being realised by -path, and for such cases the value of
will be undefined.3
It is noted, at this point, that the definition of allows arbitrary
utility functions to be employed in constructing ``worst-case'' instances. While this is reasonable
in terms of general lower bound results, as will be apparent from the given constructions the utility
functions actually employed are highly artificial (and unlikely to feature in ``real'' application settings).
We shall attempt to address this objection by further considering bounds on the following variant of
:
Thus,
deals with resource allocation settings within which all of the
utility functions must satisfy a monotonicity constraint.
The main results of this article are presented in the next sections. We consider two general
classes of contract path: -contract paths under various rationality conditions in
Section 2; and, similarly,
-contract paths
for arbitrary values of in Section 3.
Our results are concerned with the construction of
resource allocation settings
for which given
some rationality requirement, e.g. that deals be individually rational, there is some deal
that satisfies the rationality condition, can be realised by a rational -contract path (respectively,
-contract path), but with the number of deals required by such paths being exponential in .
We additionally obtain slightly weaker (but still exponential) lower bounds for rational -contract paths
within settings of monotone utility functions, i.e. for the measure
, outlining how
similar results may be derived for -contract paths.
In the resource allocation settings constructed for demonstrating these properties
with -contract paths, the constructed deal
is realisable with
a single -contract but unrealisable by any rational -contract path.
We discuss related work, in particular the recent study of Endriss-et-al:2004
that addresses similar issues to those considered in the present article, in Section 4.
Conclusions and some directions for further work are presented in the final section.
Next: Lower Bounds on Path Length
Up: Introduction
Previous: Introduction
Paul Dunne
2004-11-26